| USA China Flags Photo mamvasblogspotcom | MR Online USA / China Flags (Photo: mamvas.blogspot.com)

U.S. dooms itself to defeat in peaceful competition with China

Superficially in the recent period the U.S. has attempted to display two apparently contradictory sides of its policy to China. First hand Treasury Secretary Yellen visited China, showing off her (possibly genuine) like of Chinese food, engaging in a normal human way with various Chinese people and audiences, and presenting herself as engaging in generally calm tones on economic policy. Then, days later, Biden was staging an openly anti-China summit in Washington, with Japanese prime minister Kishida and Philippines President Marcos, and issuing political and military threats against China—which led to China’s foreign ministry spokesperson Mao Ning saying Beijing firmly opposes the relevant countries (i.e. the U.S.) manipulating bloc politics, Liu Jinsong, director general of the Department of Asian Affairs of China’s Foreign Ministry summoning the Chief Minister of the Japan’s Embassy and making representations to the Philippine ambassador to China, and to China’s Embassy in the U.S. lodging a solemn representation to Washington. This was then followed by a visit to China by Secretary of State Blinken in which he attempted to lecture China on international affairs.

In reality, this “soft cop/hard cop” U.S. approach is not contradictory. It was two sides of the same coin. In particular it is rooted in the real situation, as opposed to the myths regarding, the U.S. economy and the implications of this for U.S. foreign policy and domestic policy. These are rooted in the inability/refusal of the U.S. to abandon its aggressive military and foreign policies and a similar refusal/inability to carry out rational domestic transformations even of a reformist kind. By these the U.S. dooms itself to defeat by China in peaceful economic competition—with consequences which are examined at the end of what follows. The bulk of this article, therefore, will analyse this fundamental U.S. economic situation, in particular in its relation to China, and at its conclusion it will look at the inevitable implications of this for geopolitics and the forthcoming U.S. 2024 Presidential election.

Yellen’s visit revealed the real situation of the U.S. economy

The mere five days of Treasury Secretary Janet Yellen’s visit to China was sufficient to rip away hollow U.S. propaganda and shone a clear light on the real state of both China and the U.S. economies. The serious discussion around Yellen’s visit, because it went to the core issues, in fact was a U.S. admission that:

  • China has a large lead globally in key industries for the next stage of development of the world economy, and,
  • the U.S. is unwilling or unable, or both, to take the measures that would allow it to compete successfully.

As the U.S. was unable to peacefully compete with China it instead proposed, as on other issues, that China should commit “economic suicide” to allow the U.S. to escape the consequences of its own failures.

These economic issues also revealed an inextricable interrelation to both U.S. foreign policy and its domestic politics in the approach to the 2024 Presidential election. To analyse and untangle these economic and geopolitical issues, we well as their interrelations, we will start with the most immediate headlines and then trace the roots of these in the most fundamental forces driving them.

Cutback on green energy

As was openly publicised the purpose of in particular of Yellen’s visit, and a theme of Blinken’s, was to attempt to persuade China to cut back on the “green” industries in which it has won an overwhelming international lead. China has 80% of world production in solar panels, 60% of wind turbines, and even the Western media acknowledges China’s lead in EV and other battery production. Interrelated with this, in 2023 China became the world’s largest car exporter and in particular has the world’s leading position in EV vehicles—motor exports being previously an industry dominated by the high-income economies of Japan and Germany.

These issues, which grabbed media headlines, followed on from the publication of economic data for 2023 from the world’s main economies which showed the absurdity of recent claims in the U.S. media such as the Wall Street Journal’s that “China’s economy limps into 2024” whereas the U.S. was marked by a “resilient domestic economy” or the Washington Post’s claim “in the United States… the surprisingly strong economy is outperforming all of its major trading partners”. In fact, China’s GDP growth in 2023 was 5.2% in 2023 compared to 2.5% for the U.S.—China’s economy grew more than twice as fast as the U.S. This continued the trend over the entire four-year period since before the pandemic struck—during which period China’s 20.1% growth was two and half times that of the US’s 8.1%. This and other data was analysed in detail in 比较中国经济,某些人是如何做到“谣谣领先”的

The green transformation of the base of the world economy

But Yellen’s visit generated more headlines than did statistical data not simply because specific products such as cars, solar panels or electric batteries, are more immediately tangible and understandable to the general public than abstract concepts such as GDP. The practical reality, which directly touches billions of people, is that the entire world is going through the biggest change in its energy supply, one of the core foundations of its economy, since at least the beginning of the 20th century—when there occurred the beginning of mass electrification and the introduction of oil powered vehicles. In a more profound sense, this is the biggest transformation in this field since the Industrial Revolution created the beginning of a world energy supply based on fossil fuels—for most of the 19th century coal and then in the 20th century a mixture of coal, oil and gas.

Numerous international agreements and practical actions by national governments of course now internationally acknowledge that if catastrophic climate change is to be avoided the entire basis of the world’s energy supply will have to be rebuilt. The realisation of this is leading all major economies, including the U.S. and China, to make a transition towards renewable energy supplies—which, in the end, will involve expenditures of tens of trillions of dollars.

China’s emergence as the world’s leading supplier of green energy products therefore alters its relations with the world economy. Although since 2013 China has been the world’s largest goods trading nation its previous dominance was frequently most directly seen in fields such as medium technology or consumer goods. But the development of its new green productive forces means that China’s products are becoming increasingly essential for, and therefore integrated into, the whole process of production in other countries.

The international division of labour

Given the gigantic scale of this international economic transformation the claim by the U.S. that what is occurring is a global threat of “over production” in green products is evidently absurd—as numerous commentators have observed. On the contrary, what exists globally is a threat of insufficient production to make the shift in the necessary time period.

As China’s Vice Minister of Finance Liao Min stated: “Taking new energy vehicles as an example, according to the International Energy Agency, global demand for new energy vehicles will reach 45 million units in 2030, which is 4.5 times that of 2022; global demand for new photovoltaic installed capacity will reach 820 GW, which is 4.5 times that of 2022. The current production capacity is far from meeting market demand, especially the huge potential demand for new energy products in many developing countries.”1

Given the enormous scale of this global transformation taking place simultaneously in numerous fields it is quite clear that no single country, not even China or the U.S., can by itself meet this demand. Numerous countries will, and are, participating in this transition in different forms. Different countries will find different places in this transition according to relative advantages and efficiencies. As Vice Minister of Finance Liao Min stated: “production capacity issues should be analysed based on the global division of labour and international market conditions.”2

Similarly the U.S. claim that China should limit production to simply the scale of its domestic demand is ridiculous and is not in slightest followed by U.S. companies themselves—Reuter’s noted: “Yellen used her second trip to China in nine months to complain that Beijing’s overinvestment has built factory capacity far exceeding domestic demand.” There are numerous industries in which, for example, the U.S., Germany or Japan are enormous exporters because they have relative advantages in these industries—in the case of the U.S. these include agricultural products, civil aircraft, financial services and armaments to name only a few.

Technology boycotts

It equally follows that the idea that a country should be in balance in trade in each sector of its economy is also absurd it was refuted 250 years ago in the founding work of modern economics, Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations. On the contrary, different comparative advantages of different economies in different types of production is one of the foundations of global economic development and is a fundamental basis of high levels of international productivity and living standards. Different economies have different advantages in different spheres of production and therefore every country gains by specialising in these—while, in sectors in which they are less efficient they, it imports products from countries which are more efficient in these. These questions are clear and have been understood since the birth of economics. They form one of the key bases of the international economy.

Thus, for example, as Vice Minister of Finance Liao Min stated: “The economies of China and the United States are highly complementary, and the essence of economic and trade relations is mutual benefit and win-win.”3 To take practical examples, China is certainly the world leader in many sectors of green technology, but U.S. and Western companies at the present time retain a lead over China in production of advanced microchips and other industries. The most rational basis for development on both sides is therefore for these economies to export to each other the products in which they are most efficient and to import from other countries products which they can produce more efficiently. It is the U.S. which obstructs this through its tariffs, technology boycotts etc.

Instead, the U.S. is pursuing what is unfortunately a “lose-lose”—although one in which in the medium/long term the U.S. loses more than China. For reasons that are analysed below China has the resources to develop high tech spheres of production in which the U.S. is currently more dominant—signified dramatically, for example, in the highly successful launching of the Huawei Mate 60 Pro, openly signifying U.S. failure to destroy the mobile phone business that company via technology sanctions. In these sectors, China in the short term, of course, has to bear the cost of devoting extra resources to R&D to develop such technologies—the reasons why it can finance this are also analysed below. But in the medium/long term it is numerous U.S. and other companies participating in chip and technology boycotts against China that will be the losers because, due to the development of China’s alternatives, they will permanently lose markets for their products.

China’s balance of payments and globalization

It also follows from this long understood reality of comparative advantage and efficiency that it is ridiculous to believe there should be balanced trade in each sector of a country’s economy. Instead, the reasonable international demand, which is indeed adopted by international organisations, is that at least regarding major economies overall trade of countries should be in relative balance—that is they should not be running excessive overall balance of payments surpluses or deficits. This is clearly the case with China. In 2023, China’s current account balance of payments surplus was 1.5% of GDP—a surplus of 1,861 billion yuan compared to GDP of 126,058 billion yuan. This was actually a reduction from China’s 2.4% of GDP balance of payments surplus in 2022—although both are in an reasonable range by international criteria.

In fact, because even a cursory examination shows that its overall economic arguments make no sense, what the U.S. is worried about is its decreasing ability to maintain its position at the high end of the value chain in international trade in a widening range of products. The U.S. idea in globalisation was that it would occupy the leading position in the high technology/high value added industries and developing countries, including China, would have low and medium technology and value added industries. Correspondingly the standard of living would be high in U.S. and lower in developing countries. But, instead, China is breaking into high technology high value added industries with corresponding sharp rises in its people’s standard of living.

This in turn, of course, crucially poses the question of why the U.S. in finding itself increasingly unable to compete? It is here that the illusions of the U.S., its myths about itself, and its corresponding inability to accurately analyse problems, and therefore to overcome them, comes in. It is indeed extremely difficult for the U.S. to accurately analyse the situation because, to do so, it would have to break with delusions of U.S. supremacy and Western arrogance—something which it is very difficult psychologically and politically.

Why the U.S. finds it increasingly difficult to compete

To understand why the U.S. increasingly cannot win in peaceful competition it is necessary to analyse economic fundamentals. The U.S. authorities at present are incapable of doing this because they insist on putting forward myths which, as they conceal reality, make it incapable of focussing on its real problems. For example, the U.S. frequently claims that it will lead the world economy because it is uniquely “creative”, “innovative”, “entrepreneurial” etc. This is simply a myth. Certainly, the U.S. has extremely talented/skilled scientists, engineers, technical specialists, business leaders etc. But so does China—and India, South Korea, and other countries, and the idea that Americans are somehow more intelligent or motivated than those in other countries is simply an example of unfounded arrogance.

Attempts to present similar claims in a supposedly non-arrogant/non-racist way, by statements that U.S. institutions are superior to those of other countries, are also being tested and being shown to be false. Periodic gridlocks between different branches of U.S. government; extreme clashes between supporters of Trump and Democrats; widespread belief in fraudulent claims such as that Trump really won the 2020 presidential election; the physical attack on the U.S. legislature on 6 January 2021; the glaringly disproportionate role of money in the U.S. political system; increasingly frequent delivery by the U.S. electoral college of the Presidency to candidates defeated in the popular vote; the ability of the non-elected Supreme Court to over-rule both the legislature and overwhelming public opinion; all reflected in polling showing overwhelming lack of confidence of the population in U.S. political institutions, and a clear majority believing the country is going in the wrong direction, are signs of a dysfunctional not a well-functioning institutional system. In contrast even polls conducted by U.S. institutions find that the population of China believes its country is going in the right direction.

Regarding analysis and ideology, it is Chinese Marxism which delivered in China the greatest improvement in the living conditions of the largest number of people in human history. The U.S. simply does not have concepts in its “zero-sum” approach which allow reality to be as clearly understood as those, for example, of the “common destiny of humanity” or “common prosperity”. Factually, having achieved moderate prosperity by its national standards China, either next year or the one after, will achieve the World Bank standard of a high income economy. China will, with 18% of the world’s population, have delivered the advantages of living in a high-income economy to more people than all other countries in the world put together—the latter make up only 16% of the world’s population.

The U.S. administration cannot even acknowledge or consider the implications of such facts because to do so it would have to abandon the dreamland of myths to face the realities of the world. But, as U.S. founding father, and second President, John Adams, accurately noted: “Facts are stubborn things; and whatever may be our wishes, our inclinations, or the dictates of our passions, they cannot alter the state of facts.” Unless the U.S., or any other country, is prepared to begin to abandon myths and face economic facts it will have the utmost difficulty in solving its problems.

The development of large economies

Turning now to the real determinants of economic development as opposed to myths, particularly as regards the U.S., naturally all countries are specific and represent unique combinations of factors. China, the U.S., Japan, and Germany, to take only the four countries which together account for the majority of world GDP, are very different. But the facts demonstrate that they, and indeed all large economies, have common features. In particular, for present purposes, the facts clearly show that while numerous factors affect short term economic developments, of decisive importance in the relations of the U.S. and China is that the medium/long term growth of large economies shows an extremely close correlation between the proportion of their economy devoted to net fixed capital formation and their rate of economic development (net fixed capital formation is new investment minus the consumption of existing fixed investment through depreciation—that is the addition to the capital stock).

In order to avoid misunderstanding it should be stressed that this correlation only applies to larger economies, it does not apply to a number of small economies in which other factors, including the impact on them of large economies, can play a decisive role. But the latter point is irrelevant to both the U.S. and China as they are above all the examples of large economies—the world’s two largest economies.

To show this, Figure 1 demonstrates the pattern of growth, the relation of net fixed investment and GDP growth, in the world’s 25 largest economies over the entire period since the beginning of the international financial crisis in 2007 to the latest internationally comparable data for 2021. These economies together account for 83% of world GDP—therefore entirely dominating world economic development. Their similarity in this feature is overwhelming. The correlation between the percentage of net fixed investment in GDP and GDP growth in the world’s 25 largest economies is an astonishingly high 0.89 and the R squared is 0.79. In the real world this is as close to a perfect correlation as is likely to be found in any phenomenon.

This close relation immediately flows, in Marxist terms, from Marx’s analysis that the driving force of economic development is increasing socialisation of labour—fixed investment being simply socialisation of labour across time, i.e. the use of products of previous production cycles in the present production cycle. However, to focus attention on the facts, and make their consequences available also to those who do not accept a Marxist analysis, the terminology of “Western economics” will be used in what follows—anyone wishing to instead substitute Marxist terminology may easily do so.

| Figure 1 | MR Online

This data above makes it immediately obvious why the world’s fastest growing major economies are China and India—they have by far the highest percentages of net fixed investment in GDP. The same relation similarly shows why other major Global South economies, such as Indonesia and Turkiye, are growing much more rapidly than the U.S. or the rest of the G7—these key Global South economies have far higher levels of net fixed investment than the Global North.

Taking an example from East Asia, this same process explains why a country such as South Korea, historically much poorer than Japan, is so rapidly catching up with Japan—in 2007 South Korea’s per capita GDP, at current exchange rates, was only 67% of that of Japan whereas by 2022 it was 95%, and in PPP terms South Korea’s per capita GDP was actually 10% higher than Japan’s. These different results are explained by the fact that Japan’s level of net fixed investment has fallen to only 0.1% of GDP while South Korea’s was 11.1% of GDP—in line with this from 2007-2021 Japan’s GDP grew at an annual average rate of 0.2% while South Korea’s grew at 2.9%.

Finally, regarding this point, it is necessary to clear up some confusions, reflecting “vulgar” economics. This decisive role of net fixed investment in the economy is not counterposed to, but on the contrary is the essential complement, to “innovation”—an innovation which remains purely an idea does not produce anything, but it has to be embodied in production which will require investment (computers, microchips, solar panels, EV vehicles etc). Second, vulgar economics confuses the physical and economic meaning of the term “factor of production”—but on this issue it is the economic, the value, meaning which is decisive not the physical one. For example, a microchip is physically tiny but its value is enormously higher than a physically large product such as coal. Similarly high value-added products, requiring large investments to manufacture, such as solar panels, efficient batteries, etc far from being environmentally damaging actually are fundamental to safeguarding the environment.

China, like a number of, but unfortunately not all, major economies, is rightly turning away from methods of production which require huge accumulation of physical, and frequently environmentally damaging, factors of production—coal, fossil fuels, damage to large areas of land etc. But the products that are superseding these are in economic terms even higher value added than those which they are replacing—investment to open a coal mine is, for example, tiny compared to that required to construct a microchip factory or manufacture the most advanced form of batteries.

Causation and correlation

Turning to the practical implications of these facts for the U.S. and China, Marxist and serious Western economic theory, such as growth accounting, of course predict the factual relation shown above. They both analyse fixed investment (capital) as a key input into production. The direction of causality Marxism and serious Western economics therefore gives for the correlation is clear—increasing the level of net fixed capital formation in the economy will increase economic growth. But, for present purposes, it is not even necessary to discuss the question of causality. Such extraordinarily high correlations as those above simply mean that it is impossible to substantially raise the rate of economic growth of large economies without raising their proportion of net fixed investment in GDP—and any fall in the share of net fixed investment will be accompanied by a fall in the rate of economic growth.

The choices facing the U.S.

Now turn to the precise consequences of these facts for the U.S. The facts on the U.S. economy show that a strategy of competing with China by increasing the efficiency of U.S. investment is in reality entirely impractical. The reason for this is that China and the U.S. have, in international terms, high levels of efficiency of capital in producing economic growth—China among developing countries and the U.S. among advanced economies. The Incremental Capital Ratio (ICOR)—for non-economic specialists that is the amount of GDP that has to be allocated to gross fixed investment for their economies to grow by 1%—is 8 in the case of China and 10 in the case of the U.S. The lower the number the more efficient is investment in producing growth and the detailed comparisons may be found in “Why China’s socialist economy is more efficient than capitalism”. Both are highly efficient in producing growth in their respective categories.

Turning to net fixed investment’s efficiency in producing economic growth, the U.S. only uses 2.6% of GDP as net investment to grow its GDP by 1%—which is significantly more efficient than the median for the 25 largest economies of 3.5%. Given that U.S. investment is already efficient, realistically the only way in which the U.S. could substantially increase its economic growth rate is by increasing the percentage of net fixed investment in GDP. The very close correlations already shown then in turn make it possible to rather simply determine the orders of magnitude involved to achieve this—and immediately shows why they are inescapable interrelated with U.S. foreign and domestic policy.

Assume that the U.S. maintains this high level of efficiency of use of investment in generating economic growth. In 2007-2021 U.S. net fixed investment averaged 4.3% of GDP and its annual GDP growth rate was 1.6%—i.e., as noted earlier, U.S. GDP grew by 1% for every 2.6% of net fixed investment in GDP. To avoid the suggestion that this number is strongly affected by the period examined, shorter periods, for example, to avoid the effects of the financial crisis, produce merely marginal differences—taking the 10 years to 2021, for example, merely leads to a number of 2.5% instead of 2.6%.

To calculate from this U.S. potential economic growth rates, in the period 2007-2021 U.S. consumption of fixed capital (depreciation) was 16.1% of GDP and gross fixed capital formation was 20.5%—resulting in, rounding to one decimal point, 4.3% of net fixed investment in GDP. As the U.S. uses 2.6% of net fixed investment for its GDP to grow by 1%, assuming that the level of depreciation remains the same, and there is no realistic way to decrease this, then to increase U.S. net fixed investment to 8% of GDP would require U.S. gross fixed investment to rise from 20.5% of GDP to 24.1% —a 3.6% of GDP increase. With the same correlation of net fixed investment and GDP growth, of 2.6% of GDP having to be used to generate a 1% GDP increase, then in this case U.S. annual average GDP growth would increase to 3.1%. To raise U.S. net fixed capital formation to 10% of GDP, the share of gross fixed investment in U.S. would have to rise to 26.1% of GDP, that is by 5.6%. If that were achieved, then annual U.S. GDP growth would be 3.8%.

These are certainly significant increases, but examination of the internal structure of the U.S. economy makes clear that they are not impossible. But they would, however, require major changes in policy and the problem is that the U.S. has shown itself unwilling to make these.

Means to achieve an increase in the proportion of the U.S. economy devoted to net fixed investment

To understand the type of policy choices involved recall that investment and consumption make up 100% of the domestic economy. Therefore, ignoring inventories, which form an extremely small part of the economy, increasing the level of fixed investment in U.S. GDP would necessarily require reducing the proportion of consumption. The only choice would be which form of consumption would be reduced.

One possibility, evidently, is to significantly reduce households’ percentage of consumption in the U.S. economy. But this would mean a sharp short-term reduction in household consumption, and therefore U.S. living standards, which would be very unpopular—very difficult for a U.S. administration to gain assent to. But there are other ways to reduce the share of consumption in the U.S. economy, and therefore raise the U.S. investment rate, without decreasing the share of household consumption.

The first is military spending—military spending in economic terms is overwhelmingly a form of consumption (on official U.S. data 78% of U.S. military spending is consumption). In 2023, on its official figures, U.S. military spending was 3.6% of GDP—$995 billion. Reduction of U.S. military spending would, therefore, release very considerable resources for U.S. investment. For example, reducing U.S. military expenditure to the 2% of GDP which it is the level the U.S. urges for its NATO allies, would release 1.6% of GDP for investment—almost half of the resources required to raise U.S. net fixed capital investment to 8% of GDP.

In reality, there is considerably greater scope for savings as U.S. official data substantially understates its level of military spending by excluding items such as military pensions, debt payments on borrowing for military expenditure etc from its official data. As the recent study of the U.S. national accounts by Gisela Cernadas and John Bellamy Foster found, in 2022 real U.S. military expenditure was $1,537 billion (or 5.6% of GDP) as opposed to the official figure of $928 billion (or 3.6% of GDP).

The second area in which the U.S. could release huge resources for investment is in health spending due to the extraordinarily inefficient U.S. health system. The U.S. private health system uses by far the highest proportion of economic resources, for the worst outcome, of any comparable economy. World Bank data shows that in 2019, before the huge increases in expenditure in almost every country due to the impact of Covid, 16.7% of U.S. GDP was spent on health—compared to, for example, taking economies at comparable levels of development, 11.7% of GDP in Germany, 11.1% in France, 10.8% in Japan or 9.9% in the UK.

But the outcomes of this private U.S. health system are far worse than in other countries—U.S. life expectancy in 2019 was 78.8 years, compared to 81.3 years in Germany, 84.4 years in Japan, 81.4 years in in the UK, or 82.3 years in France.

Adopting the public centred health systems used in other countries would release enormous resources to increase U.S. investment. For example, reducing U.S. health expenditure to German levels would release 5% of GDP—or by itself enough to raise the U.S. level of net fixed investment to 8% of GDP. A combination of reducing U.S. military expenditure, and rationalisation of its extraordinarily inefficient health system, would easily release sufficient resources to hugely increase U.S. investment.

In summary, in looking at how to increase U.S. economic growth rates and competivity, it might be too radical a solution for the U.S. to adopt socialism! But the acute form of these problems for the U.S. arises from the fact that it won’t even undertake rational reforms within the framework of the capitalist system.

In turn, the reason the U.S. administration is unwilling/unable to undertake these changes is because they would require changes in U.S. foreign and domestic policy. Significantly reducing military expenditure would put pressure on the U.S. to make its foreign policy less aggressive. Rationalising the U.S. health system, moving towards the more successful ones of other comparable countries, would require confronting vested interests among U.S. private health providers and using elements of public supply of health services which are declared to be unacceptably “socialist” by U.S. ideology.

In short, the increasing inability of the U.S. to compete in investment in developing new industries is not due to China, it is due to its own economic choices. The problem is made in Washington, not in Beijing.

Equally, of course, anyone in the U.S. who wants reforms to develop green industries, good jobs and peacefully competitive industry will point out the changes in U.S. military, foreign and health policies these require. The U.S. problems in these key fields are not because of China but because the U.S. refuses to change its military policy, its foreign policy, or its extraordinarily inefficient health system.

U.S. losing its competitive position

Finally, to bring these macro-economic issues down to the company/industry level, consider their financial implications—which leads directly to the core question. Macro-economically all investment must necessarily have an equal quantity of savings/capital creation (here it should be noted that, in economic terms, savings are not simply those by households but also those from company profits and any by government—in practical terms savings by governments are typically negative, due to their budget deficits).

In every major economy the overwhelming majority of such savings/capital creation are from within their own economy. The U.S. is unusual in that in 2023 it used $845 billion from abroad, equivalent to 3.1% of GDP, to finance its investment but this still means that 84% of U.S. gross fixed investment was financed domestically. The low level of fixed investment in the U.S., compared to China, therefore reflects the U.S. low level of capital creation/savings—in 2022, the last year for which there is internationally comparable data, China’s capital creation/savings was 47.0% of GDP compared to 17.1% for the U.S.

To accurately assess the enormous impact of this on international economic competition a more illustrative measure is to show this in in dollar terms. Figure 2 shows that in 2022 China’s capital creation/savings was $8.4 trillion compared to $4.6 trillion for the U.S. In absolute terms China’s savings/capital creation was therefore 194%, that is almost double, that of the U.S. Indeed, China’s capital creation/savings is larger than the U.S. and the Eurozone combined.

| Figure 2 | MR Online

U.S. lack of competivity spreads to new industries

It is China’s huge lead in capital creation/savings available for investment that in turn makes possible its lead in the development of new industries. And it is the lack of such resources which means that the U.S. finds itself unable to compete in a steadily widening range of industries.

Every new industry, every new productive force, requires investment. China therefore has an unequalled ability to allocate resources to such emerging new industries. As Vice Minister Liao Min put it: “China’s new energy industry has experienced rapid development for decades. Its current competitive advantages are rooted in China’s large-scale market advantages, complete industrial system and abundant human resources. It is also inseparable from the huge investment in R&D and innovation by enterprises and the unremitting efforts of entrepreneurs.”4

The U.S. is falling behind in creating such resources for investment and therefore has increasing difficulty to allocate them to new industries. Furthermore, as already seen, the U.S. is unwilling to take the steps that would create the resources that would allow it to do so.

This process creates the powerful development of new productive forces in China—China’s transition to becoming a technological leader. This process is, consequently, inevitable spreading out from one industry to many. It was already achieved in telecommunications—U.S. sanctions against Huawei are in fact an admission Western companies cannot compete with it. Furthermore. telecommunications is integral to the development of a whole series of IT sectors. China’s lead in green power, battery production and motor exports has already been noted. In consumer products the attempt to ban TikTok is once again a U.S. admission that it cannot compete with what is now one of the world’s leading retail products. China and the U.S. are the world’s two leaders in Artificial Intelligence.

But inevitably this process will not stop at its present stage. There will inevitably be the emergence of new industries, technologies, and products which are not yet even invented. China has the resources to invest in these on a scale which the U.S. does not.

If the U.S. already finds China in the technological lead in a number of industries today, then in the future it will be in many more. And while the U.S. can take action against individual companies today, such as Huawei or TikTok, in the future the processes already outlined mean China will have far too many such companies for this to be effective. What was originally U.S. attempts to suppress one or two companies will begin to come close to suppressing whole new industries in which they U.S. cannot compete—the world is already halfway there in this in the case of renewable energy for example.

The U.S. also finds itself in an increasingly difficult situation due to the wholly global development of new industries. If the U.S. decides to lock its own economy into high cost/relatively inefficient production behind tariffs, there may be nothing China can do about it except point out the self-harming character of such developments. But most of the world, outside the closest circles of U.S. allies, won’t go along with it. Why should any country aiming at national development decide to purchase more expensive products from the U.S. when products with exactly the same technical capacity, and in a number of cases superior ones, can be obtained from China? Even if the U.S. decides to cut itself off from China, and even this is by no means practically easy to achieve, as long as China maintains its present dynamic the majority of the world economy will not.

The U.S. situation is worsening

What makes this situation more acute is that the U.S. position is deteriorating, not improving. To see this Figure 3 is the most important graph to understand the US’s economic rise and fall over the last century. It can be easily seen that at the peak of its power, as it emerged from the Great Depression, World War II, and during the post-World War II economic boom, U.S. net fixed investment as a proportion of its economy did in fact reach the levels for more rapid economic growth analysed above. In 1943, at the peak of the U.S. World War II boom, the fastest period of economic growth in its entire history, U.S. net fixed investment rose to 14.8% of GDP. In 1966, during the post war boom, U.S. net fixed investment was 10.9% of GDP. But by 2023, after almost six decades of decline, U.S. fixed investment had fallen to a mere 4.4% of GDP. Due to the processes analysed above, unless the U.S. reverses this trend it is incapable of regaining rapid economic growth or to have the resources to successfully compete in a widening range of new industries.

| Figure 3 | MR Online

The U.S. is locked into slow economic growth

The practical consequences of this economic trend in terms of development are clear. It is an inevitable result of the relations note above, that as the proportion of net fixed investment in U.S. GDP fell so also did its economic growth rate. Figure 4 shows this process, with the long-term annual rate of U.S. GDP growth declining inexorably, as its net investment as a share of its economy fell, from 6.3% of GDP in 1953, to 4.4% in 1969, to 4.0% in 1978, to 3.5% in 2002, to 2.1% in 2023. As the U.S. is unwilling to take the measures to raise its level of net fixed capital formation in GDP the factual relations above mean it is inescapably locked into a slow growth rate and having increasing difficulty in financing development of new productive forces.

| Figure 4 | MR Online

Therefore, try to persuade China to commit suicide—consumption

Finally on these directly economic issues, as the U.S. is unwilling/unable to take the measures to increase its level of net fixed investment in GDP and has no way to “murder” China’s economy, the only way the U.S. can attempt to compete with China is to ask China to commit economic “suicide”. Specifically, this means, that China should reduce its level of investment down towards the level of the U.S. As the U.S., evidently, cannot openly ask China to do this as a proposal to commit economic suicide, the U.S. instead puts this in the form of asking China to raise the proportion of consumption in its economy—as consumption and investment together make up 100% of the domestic economy increasing the percentage of consumption in GDP necessarily means reducing the proportion of investment.

An extended analysis of this issue was given in “So-Called ‘Peak China’ Is Simply a Western Campaign for China to Commit Economic Suicide” so it is unnecessary to repeat this here. It is sufficient to note that in her visit to China Yellen continued this line of attack. As the New York Times noted: “During her meetings with her Chinese counterparts, Ms. Yellen tried to argue that China should focus more on… consumption.” The Washington Post similarly emphasised that Yellen argued:

Chinese authorities should boost domestic consumption.

Conclusion—implications for U.S. foreign policy and domestic politics

We will conclude briefly with the implications of this for U.S. foreign and domestic politics.

The best interests of the world, China, and the U.S. people would clearly be served by U.S. administrations abandoning their “zero-sum” approach to international relations and understanding, as demonstrated in China’s central foreign policy concept of the “common destiny of humanity”, that cooperation between countries is the best basis of mutual advantage and advance. But, as at present, U.S. governments are not prepared to do this, the US’s successive lines of attack on China flow inevitably from the situation which was seen above and explain its recent diplomatic and other actions.

First, for the reasons analysed above, unless the U.S. undertakes the types of economic change which will produce a sharp increase in its level of investment, and if China refuses to change course to commit economic suicide, then the defeat of the U.S. in peaceful economic competition is inevitable.

Second, as the U.S. has been unwilling/unable to take the necessary economic measures required for success in developing new global industries, the US’s least risky choice, at present, to try to win in such competition, is to attempt to persuade China to commit economic suicide by a radical increase in the share of consumption in its economy radical reduction in its level of investment. The U.S. realises it faces formidable obstacle in this because Xi Jinping has stressed that China must base itself on Marxist economics, “our study of political economy must be based on Marxist political economy and not any other economic theory”,5 and even serious “Western” economics totally contradicts the policies which the U.S. is urging on China—for a detailed analysis of this see “So-Called ‘Peak China’ Is Simply a Western Campaign for China to Commit Economic Suicide”. But, nevertheless, the U.S. hopes that some combination of confused theories, comprador elements, those who wish to emulate Russian oligarchs who became rich through the national catastrophe of Russia, or other forces might be able to persuade China onto such a path. It was to encourage this that Yellen was attempting to spread confusion and damaging economic policies during her visit. As other alternatives are more dangerous for the U.S., and external economic sanctions are not powerful enough to derail China, then for a period the U.S.t is likely to continue to have as its main tactic this attempt to get China to commit economic suicide.

Third, however, the U.S. is likely to fail in this course. Therefore, it has to prepare more dangerous options both for everyone else—and also for itself. These options flow from the fact that while the U.S. is losing in peaceful economic competition it still possesses the world’s most powerful military—U.S. military spending is larger than the next nine countries put together. However, this situation will inevitably change, including in the nuclear field, as China’s economic success translates into military strengthening—and given the U.S. record of military aggression in Korea, Vietnam, Iraq, Libya and elsewhere the threat of its own nuclear annihilation is the most trustworthy restraint on the U.S. In the present situation, the danger is that the U.S. will decide it will take the risk of military or military related solutions before it loses its lead in this field. Such a course, of military related actions around China’s Taiwan Province, or even war, is actively advocated by a minority within the U.S. foreign policy/military mainstream. It runs in parallel with policies such as the provocations in the South China Sea symbolised by the recent U.S.-Japan-Philippines summit. How to deal with military related threats is, of course, only a matter for China itself and requires information only available to a country’s leaders. But in general, viewed from outside, given the military threats from the U.S. it is evident that the attention being paid by the leadership of the CPC to national security is entirely justified.

Fourth, this increasing turn of the U.S. to military related policies is both leading to international crises and has a major impact in U.S. domestic politics. Numerous U.S. experts on Eastern Europe warned that the attempt by the U.S. to expand NATO up to the borders of Russia would inevitably lead to a deep crisis. This duly broke out in Ukraine in the largest war in Europe since 1945, but one which at present Russia is winning. In West Asia (the “Middle East”), U.S. support for Israel’s polices, including that country’s most extreme government ever under Netanyahu, led first to armed conflict on 7 October and now to the prolonged war in Gaza and the massacres carried out there by Israel. These actions by Israel, in turn, have led not only to immense human suffering but also extremely widespread global revulsion against its policies, and therefore international isolation of the U.S. for supporting and providing the means for Israel to carry out these actions. These unfolding massacres in Gaza have in turn now created widespread opposition to Israel’s policy even within the U.S. itself.. In short, an increasing resort to military related solutions, has damaged the U.S. internationally and is impacting U.S. domestic politics and the 2024 Presidential election. Unfortunately, however, instead of retreating from such policies, and addressing itself to dealing with its real economic problems, analysed above, the U.S. is attempting to double down on aggressive military related policies— as shown at the Philippines-Japan-US summit and in proposals to expand the AUKUS alliance to include Japan.

Therefore, as stated at the beginning of this article, Yellen’s visit and the bellicose rhetoric of the Biden-Kishida-Marcos summit are not contradictory but are the two sides of the same coin inevitably produced by the fundamental economic situation of the U.S.

The Chinese version of this article was originally published at Guancha.cn.


Notes:

  1. 财政部副部长廖岷就美国财政部部长耶伦访华情况向媒体吹风并答问 https://www.guancha.cn/internation/2024_04_08_730981.shtml
  2. 财政部副部长廖岷就美国财政部部长耶伦访华情况向媒体吹风并答问 https://www.guancha.cn/internation/2024_04_08_730981.shtml
  3. 财政部副部长廖岷就美国财政部部长耶伦访华情况向媒体吹风并答问 https://www.guancha.cn/internation/2024_04_08_730981.shtml
  4. 财政部副部长廖岷就美国财政部部长耶伦访华情况向媒体吹风并答问 https://www.guancha.cn/internation/2024_04_08_730981.shtml
  5. Xi, J. (2020, October 11). Opening Up New Frontiers for Marxist Political Economy in Contemporary China (November 23, 2015). Retrieved from Qiushi: http://en.qstheory.cn/2020-11/08/c_560906.htm